Home Current Issue Previous Issues Published Ahead-of-Print Collections For Authors Journal Info
Skip Navigation LinksHome > March 13, 2013 - Volume 27 - Issue 5 > The cost-effectiveness of expanded HIV screening in the Unit...
AIDS:
doi: 10.1097/QAD.0b013e32835c54f9
Epidemiology and Social

The cost-effectiveness of expanded HIV screening in the United States

Lucas, Aaron; Armbruster, Benjamin

Free Access
Supplemental Author Material
Article Outline
Collapse Box

Author Information

Department of Industrial Engineering and Management Science, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois, USA.

Correspondence to Aaron Lucas, Department of Industrial Engineering and Management Science, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL 60208, USA. Tel: +1 610 308 1471; e-mail: aalucas@u.northwestern.edu

Received 21 August, 2012

Revised 25 October, 2012

Accepted 6 November, 2012

Supplemental digital content is available for this article. Direct URL citations appear in the printed text and are provided in the HTML and PDF versions of this article on the journal's Website (http://www.AIDSonline.com).

Collapse Box

Abstract

Objective: The current Centers of Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) guidelines from 2006 recommend a one-time test for low-risk individuals and annual testing for those at high risk. These guidelines may not be aggressive enough, even for those at low risk of infection, due to the earlier initiation of HAART and a movement towards a test-and-treat environment. We evaluated the optimal testing frequencies for various risk groups in comparison to the CDC recommendations.

Methods: We build a deterministic mathematical model optimizing the tradeoff between the societal cost of testing and the benefits over a patient's lifetime of earlier diagnosis.

Results: Under a test-and-treat scenario with immediate initiation of HAART, the optimal testing frequency is every 2.4 years for low-risk (0.01% annual incidence) individuals; every 9 months for moderate risk (0.1% incidence) individuals; and every 3 months for high-risk (1.0% incidence) individuals. The incremental cost-effectiveness of the optimal policy is $36 342/quality-adjusted life-years (QALY) for low-risk individuals and $45 074/QALY for high-risk individuals compared with 20-year and annual testing, respectively.

Conclusion: The current CDC guidelines for HIV testing are too conservative, and more frequent testing is cost-effective for all risk groups.

Back to Top | Article Outline

Introduction

Frequent HIV testing in healthcare settings is an effective method for identifying new HIV infections before substantial declines in CD4+ T-lymphocyte counts occur [1–4]. Avoiding late diagnosis allows for an earlier initiation of HAART, which substantially reduces HIV transmission in addition to increasing survival [5,6]. There is a growing consensus that initiating HAART immediately after detection is beneficial regardless of a patient's CD4+ T-lymphocyte count. In fact, according to the recent US Department of Health and Human Services (DHHS) guidelines, HIV-positive individuals are eligible for antiretrovirals, no matter their CD4+ T-lymphocyte count [7]. Early detection of HIV through frequent testing also promotes risk reduction in previously undiagnosed HIV-positive patients by decreasing partnership acquisition rates and increasing safe sex practices with perceived HIV-negative partners [8].

In 2006, the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) released recommendations on universal voluntary opt-out HIV testing in healthcare settings for adolescents and adults [9]. The CDC recommended that all adolescents and adults who have not been tested before should be offered a test and that high-risk individuals should be tested at least annually. The recommendations consider high-risk individuals to be IDUs, and their sex partners, sex workers, sex partners of HIV-infected persons and individuals who themselves or their sex partner have multiple partners. In addition, the CDC recommended in 2011 that it would likely be beneficial for MSM to screen every 3–6 months [10].

The 2006 CDC recommendations are based on articles by Walensky et al.[11], Sanders et al.[3] and Paltiel et al.[2] examining the cost-effectiveness of routine HIV testing in the out-patient setting. However, since the publication of these articles in 2005, the guidelines for initiating HAART have changed substantially. The International AIDS Society–USA Panel recommends initiating HAART at a CD4+ T-lymphocyte count of 500 cells/μl [12]. Given the accelerated rate at which new, safer and more effective drugs are entering the market and the recent finding that HAART reduces the risk of transmitting the virus by 96%, it is not unreasonable to conceive of recommendations to initiate treatment immediately after diagnosis in the near future [6]. In addition, the study by Paltiel et al.[2] assumed all individuals background test every 5 years. They state that this agrees with the observation in the medical community that it takes on average 5 years from infection to detection. However, testing every 5 years with a constant probability of background testing implies approximately 2.5 years from infection to detection.

Our goal is to determine whether HIV testing in healthcare settings should be more aggressive than currently recommended. Although we assume a more liberal treatment scenario in which a patient enters treatment immediately after detection, we consider in the sensitivity analysis waiting to initiate treatment until the CD4+ T-lymphocyte count drops to 500 cells/μl. To investigate this, we use a simple mathematical model to evaluate the optimal frequency of HIV testing under various incidence rates, which serve as proxies for risk groups. Our analysis includes the monetary costs and health costs from both the individual tested and from preventing secondary infections.

Back to Top | Article Outline

Materials and methods

Our analysis uses quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs) as the measure of effectiveness. We seek to find an optimal time between HIV tests, which minimizes the total lifetime discounted societal monetary and health costs incurred from an individual using a cost–benefit analysis. For that purpose, we convert QALYs into health costs by using q, the dollar value for one QALY. We later use actual QALYs to calculate cost-effectiveness ratios.

Table 1 lists the main parameters of the model [13–15]. We let r denote the annual discount rate for monetary and health costs; τ denote the duration a person is sexually active during their lifetime; q denote the cost-effectiveness threshold; and C denote the cost of an HIV test. Monetary costs are inflated to 2010 dollars using the medical care component of the CPI-U [16]. For our cost–benefit analysis, we use a baseline value of q equal to $163 880 equal to one QALY [13]. As the value q equal to $50 000 is used abundantly in the medical literature, we consider this value in the sensitivity analysis [17]. The baseline cost of a rapid HIV antibody test is C equal to $16 [14], and in the sensitivity analysis, we consider a cost of $56 [18] and $42 [18]. We let h denote the incidence of HIV infection for the population of interest. We consider annual rates of 0.01, 0.1 and 1% to serve as proxies for low, moderate and high-risk groups, respectively. Recent estimates for HIV incidence in the United States among those aged 13 years and older peg the overall rate at 0.02% [19,20], with the incidence rate among whites at 0.01% and among blacks at 0.07% [20]. The incidence among MSM is even higher. MSM compose the largest group of new HIV infections [19] and have an average incidence of 0.7% [21]. In some urban populations, MSM incidence even reaches 2–3% [22].

Table 1
Table 1
Image Tools

We now define the total discounted net lifetime monetary, Fc(t), and health costs in QALYs, Fh(t), of detecting HIV t years after infection in an individual. These functions capture the costs not only to the person diagnosed but also those from secondary infections. We are particularly interested in the slopes of these functions, fc and fh, respectively, because they describe the monetary and health costs of delaying diagnosis by 1 year (and thus delaying treatment in a test-and-treat environment). We combine these into a total marginal cost of detection (MCD) using the dollar amount of one QALY, q, so that the MCD = f = fc+qfh. Our assumption that fc and fh are independent of t [i.e. that Fc(t) and Fh(t) are close to linear] is reasonable due to the lack of better data and because we expect the rate of secondary infections to be constant during the long, chronic stage of untreated HIV infection. Although the acute, primary stage of HIV infection accounts for a disparately large amount of secondary infections, we assume that standard antibody tests rolled out during a test-and-treat policy likely do not detect HIV infection before the chronic stage begins. Using Supplementary Table 1, http://links.lww.com/QAD/A277, we estimate baseline values of these key parameters, fc = −$5304 and fh = 0.41 QALYs, indicating that delaying the detection of an individual HIV infection by 1 year saves society $5304 and costs it 0.41 QALYs, yielding a total MCD of f = $61 293 for each year of delay.

We assume that individuals are initially HIV-negative, a conservative assumption that underestimates the value of testing; that the annual probability of infection, h, remains constant; that the testing is close to 100% accurate [23–25]; and that HAART reduces secondary transmission to a negligible rate [6]. Another key assumption is that HIV-positive individuals may begin HAART immediately after diagnosis. In the sensitivity analysis, we examine a scenario in which HIV-positive individuals only begin HAART at a CD4+ T-lymphocyte count of 500 cells/μl. In that scenario, we assume that between the time of diagnosis and the initiation of HAART, the individual receives no direct benefit from knowing their status but reduces their risky behaviour by 20% [26,27]. We use a CD4+ T-lymphocyte count of 750 cells/μl immediately after seroconversion [28,29], with an average yearly CD4 cell count decline of 75 cells/μl [28,30–32] to estimate that the time from infection to a CD4+ T-lymphocyte count of 500 cells/μl is 3.3 years. As we seek to capture all the relevant costs, we do not include additional background testing in our model unlike the one by Paltiel et al.[2].

A concern with implementing an effective test-and-treat scenario is timely linkage to care and sustained engagement in care for HIV-diagnosed individuals [33]. Sustained engagement includes not just linking to HIV care, but full retention in care and adequate adherence to antiretroviral medication. A recent meta-analysis of linkage to care studies conducted after 2003 found that only 72% of those diagnosed as HIV-positive were properly linked to care and only 42% had multiple HIV medical care visits during a specified assessment interval [34]. Moreover, even after the facilitation of a connection between an HIV patient and provider, the patient's long-term retention into care and the patient's adherence to antiretroviral treatment remains uncertain. To model this uncertainty, we create a parameter p for the probability with which a patient is linked to and fully engaged in HIV care soon after diagnosis. This probabilty is hard to pinpoint, and so, we examine p at a low value of 0.3 and a higher value of 0.9 in the sensitivity analysis; we fix P equal to 1 at baseline. The required modification of the model is detailed in the supplement.

We let T denote the time between HIV tests. We examine the trade-off between the cost of testing for HIV and the cost of delaying detection. Our goal is to seek the time between HIV tests, T*, which minimizes g(T), the expected societal discounted lifetime combined monetary and health cost per person. The details of calculating T* are provided in the supplement. Nevertheless, there is also a simple formula (see the supplement for details, http://links.lww.com/QAD/A277) to approximate T* within 3% of its true value:

Equation (Uncited)
Equation (Uncited)
Image Tools

We may also revert to the original fc and fh to perform a cost-effectiveness analysis with QALYs as the measure of effectiveness. Using the approximation in Equation (1) (details are provided in the supplement, http://links.lww.com/QAD/A277), we can approximate the incremental cost-effectiveness ratio of testing every T2 years instead of every T1 years as

Equation (Uncited)
Equation (Uncited)
Image Tools

We use a 20-year testing frequency as our reference group in our analysis to serve as a proxy for testing once in a lifetime, as 20 years is half of our baseline sexual lifespan.

Back to Top | Article Outline

Results

Figure 1 shows the optimal time between tests, T*, as a function of the annual incidence rate, h. In a low-risk population with an annual incidence of 0.01%, the optimal testing frequency is approximately every 2.4 years. In medium and high-risk populations with an annual incidence of 0.1 and 1%, the optimal testing frequency is approximately every 9 and every 3 months, respectively.

Fig. 1
Fig. 1
Image Tools

Figure 2 shows the incremental cost-effectiveness of different testing frequencies compared with testing every 20 years for low, medium and high-risk populations. We use a 20-year testing frequency as our reference group to serve as a conservative proxy for a once in a lifetime test. At $100 000 per QALY, annual testing is cost-effective for medium and high-risk groups, whereas every 3 years is cost-effective for low-risk groups. At $50 000 per QALY, testing low-risk groups every 5 years is cost-effective. For the high-risk group, the ICER is almost constant until we reach an annual testing frequency, whereas for the low-risk group, the ICER increases rapidly as the testing frequency increases. Furthermore, moving from testing every 20 years (a conservative proxy for the current policy for low-risk individuals) to testing with our model's optimal testing frequency of every 2.4 years results in a gain of 0.006 QALYs at a cost of $213.68 per person. Similarly, testing high-risk individuals every 3 months compared with annual testing yields a gain of 0.03 QALYs at a cost of $1357 per person.

Fig. 2
Fig. 2
Image Tools

The approximation in Equation (1) provides a simple description of how the optimal testing frequency changes under different scenarios. For example, doubling the cost of an HIV test causes the optimal time between tests to increase by a factor of approximately

Equation (Uncited)
Equation (Uncited)
Image Tools

, whereas doubling the MCD, f, for the same incidence rate reduces the optimal time between tests by a factor of

Equation (Uncited)
Equation (Uncited)
Image Tools

. Table 2 shows the optimal testing frequency under different scenarios. The optimal testing frequency is relatively unchanged if we use vastly different sexual lifespans; if we increase the average annual cost of managing HIV infection from $23 007 per year to $25 000; or if we decrease the loss in life-years and QALYs from delaying treatment initiation 1 year from 0.35 to 0.2. The optimal time between tests drops by one-third if we decrease the HIV-positive life expectancy from 37 to 18 years. In addition, the optimal time between tests increases by roughly two-thirds if the cost of testing increases to $42 from $16 and by a half if the rate secondary cases falls to 0.02 per infected person per year from 0.04. The optimal time between tests approximately doubles if we decrease the cost-effectiveness threshold to $50 000 per QALY and almost doubles if we delay the initiation of treatment until the CD4+ T-lymphocytes count falls below 500 cells/μl. With a 30% rate of successful linkage and retention in care, the time between tests becomes 4.4, 1.3 and 0.4 years for those at high, moderate and low-risk, respectively. The closest we get to reproducing the testing frequencies recommended by Paltiel et al.[2] and Sanders et al.[3] is by assuming an MCD of $3000, significantly lower than the baseline value of $61 293.

Table 2
Table 2
Image Tools

We lastly compare the aggregate societal gain in moving from the CDC recommendations to our model's optimal testing frequency [approximated by Equation (2)]. The gain in moving from testing every 20 years (a conservative proxy for the current the CDC's recommendations) to the optimal testing frequency of every 2.4 years for one million low-risk individuals in the United States would be 5880 QALYs at a cost of $213.7 million or $36 342 per each additional QALY. The CDC estimates that MSM account for 2% of the United States population, or roughly 6 million people [30]. Assuming a 1.0% incidence for MSM, moving from the 2006 recommendations of annual testing to testing every 3 months would avert a loss of 180 636 QALYs in this population at a cost of $8.1 billion or $45 074 per each additional QALY.

Back to Top | Article Outline

Discussion

We used a simple mathematical model to calculate optimal HIV testing frequencies for different risk groups using HIV incidence rates as proxies. This model focuses on the tradeoff between delaying detection of HIV and the cost of testing. In our baseline calculations, we assume that an HIV-positive patient undergoes treatment immediately after diagnosis. Under this scenario, we find that even low-risk individuals may benefit from testing more often than every 3 years. This finding stands out from the once in a lifetime test that the CDC recommends. We show that moderate risk individuals should test every 9 months. This finding supports the notion that the CDC should address those falling between high and low risk, as these individuals are not directly touched upon in the 2006 recommendations. We finally find that the high-risk individuals should test every 3 months. The last recommendation agrees with the recent update from the CDC advising MSM to consider testing every 3–6 months [10], and our findings suggest a large societal health benefit from incorporating this update into the official CDC HIV testing recommendations. Overall, our model explicitly demonstrates that a more aggressive shift towards more frequent testing would save many QALYs at a relatively low cost to society.

Our one-way sensitivity analysis shows our findings to be relatively robust. Particularly encouraging was the fact that the remaining sexual lifespan did not significantly change our results, implying that age is not an important factor. The current recommendations of the International AIDS Society - USA Panel are to initiate treatment when the CD4+ T-lymphocytes count falls below 500 cells/μl, though it is conceivable that that in the future, the recommendation will be to initiate treatment immediately after diagnosis. If we assume that treatment may only be initiated at a CD4+ T-lymphocytes count of 500 cells/μl (approximately 3.3 years after infection), we still find an optimal testing frequency of every 5 years, which is much more frequent than than the once in a lifetime test currently recommended for low-risk individuals. Even in a setting with a low rate of linkage and retention in care, we still find an optimal testing interval of every 4.4 years for those at low risk and 1.3 years for those at moderate risk. Thus, even in settings with poor rates of follow-up, those at moderate or high risk should be tested close to annually.

Our model finds it optimal to test much more frequently than what Paltiel et al.[2] and Sanders et al.[3] suggest. In addition, our ICERs for testing every 5 years instead of every 20 years are significantly lower than the ICERs in the studies by Paltiel et al.[2] and Sanders et al.[3] for testing every 5 years instead of once (they did not consider every 20 years). This implies a much lower MCD of $3000, compared with our baseline value of $61 293. Unfortunately, due to the complexities of the models in Paltiel et al.[2] and Sanders et al.[3], we cannot pinpoint a reason for the discrepancy.

Now, we turn to the limitations of our model. The first limitation is that similar to the earlier models, we assume that each individual experiences a constant hazard rate of becoming infected. However, the risk of infection in a monogamous partnership may decrease over time, as it becomes more and more certain that both individuals are likely to be HIV negative. Thus, the assumption of a constant hazard rate may be invalid when the partner turnover is very low. Thus, testing recommendations for very low-risk groups may be better phrased not as a test every T years but as a test every n partners. The assumption of a constant hazard rate also becomes invalid when a person's risk profile changes over their sexually active lifetime (e.g. when they enter a long-term monogamous relationship). However, one can always change the person's recommended testing frequency as their risk profile changes. The second limitation is that our calculation of the incremental net monetary and health costs did not capture any symptomatic case finding. However, symptoms are unlikely to develop before detection by routine testing with the frequencies we suggest. Third, we do not address costs associated with a positive HIV test, including initial posttest counselling. These, however, are fixed costs for every newly diagnosed HIV-positive person and thus do not affect the optimal value in our equations. Fourth, we briefly mention the ‘window period’ of standard antibody HIV tests in the introduction that they often do not detect infections in the acute stage (infections within 1–3 months for standard tests). However, this is not a limitation of our model, as adding the window period into our model would only shift our equations by a constant and not affect the MCD and thus would not affect the optimal testing frequencies. Fifth, we acknowledge that although our baseline assumes a test-and-treat scenario, such a testing environment is not yet a reality in every healthcare setting. However, this scenario is quickly approaching as evidenced by the recent DHHS guidelines of initiating ART regardless of a patient's CD4+ T-lymphocytes count [7]. Thus, our findings are directly applicable if a particular healthcare setting follows the DHHS guidelines. Finally, although we do take into account the present value of any future costs associated with HIV diagnosis, we acknowledge both the complexity and uncertainty surrounding the long-term projections of these costs in treating HIV-positive individuals. However, it is likely that HIV antibody test costs will decrease as time progresses. Moreover, even if costs associated with HAART increase, the benefits of early diagnosis with respect to extending survival and secondary infections will still persist.

We have discussed the limitations of two studies [2,3] that influenced the 2006 CDC guidelines on routine HIV testing in healthcare settings [9]. Those reasons and the recommendations for earlier initiation of treatment [12] led us to develop a straightforward mathematical model to suggest new policies. Our model uses a multipronged approach. We implemented a cost–benefit analysis to determine the optimal time between HIV tests for individuals by risk group and a cost-effectiveness analysis to demonstrate the improvement in moving from the CDC recommendations to our model's recommendations. Our results conclusively showed that the 2006 CDC HIV testing recommendations are too conservative, especially for low-risk groups who would benefit from more frequent testing. These results should encourage policymakers and medical professionals to reconsider how often adults and adolescents should be tested for HIV.

Back to Top | Article Outline

Acknowledgements

The authors received no funding for this report. All authors contributed equally to the report. The authors thank Sabina Alistar and Rebecca Wurtz for helpful comments and suggestions.

There was no funding for this report.

The study was presented at the 33rd Annual Meeting of the Society for Medical Decision Making on 24 October 2011 in Chicago, Illinois, USA.

Back to Top | Article Outline
Conflicts of interest

The authors have no commercial or other association that would pose a conflict of interest.

Back to Top | Article Outline

References

1. Lyons MS, Lindsell CJ, Deanna RN, Hawkins A, Rn DLR, Trott AT, Fichtenbaum CJ. Contributions to early HIV diagnosis among patients linked to care vary by testing venue. BMC Public Health 2008; 8:220.

2. Paltiel AD, Weinstein MC, Kimmel AD, Seage R, George R, Losina E, et al. Expanded screening for HIV in the United States: an analysis of cost-effectiveness. N Engl J Med 2005; 352:586–595.

3. Sanders GD, Bayoumi AM, Sundaram V, Bilir SP, Neukermans CP, Rydzak CE, et al. Cost-effectiveness of screening for HIV in the era of highly active antiretroviral therapy. N Engl J Med 2005; 352:570–585.

4. Walensky RP, Freedberg KA, Weinstein MC, Paltiel AD. Cost-effectiveness of HIV testing and treatment in the United States. Clinical infectious diseases: an official publication of the Infectious Diseases Society of America 2007; 45 (Suppl 4):S248–S254.

5. Cain LE, Logan R, Robins JM, Sterne JA, Sabin C. others. When to initiate combined antiretroviral therapy to reduce mortality and AIDS-defining illness in HIV-infected persons in developed countries: an observational study. Ann Intern Med 2011; 154:509–515.

6. Cohen MS, Chen YQ, McCauley M, Gamble T, Hosseinipour MC, Kumarasamy N, et al. Prevention of HIV-1 infection with early antiretroviral therapy. N Engl J Med 2011; 365:493–505.

7. Panel on Antiretroviral Guidelines for Adults and Adolescents. Guidelines for the use of antiretroviral agents in HIV-1-infected adults and adolescents.http://www.aidsinfo.nih.gov/ContentFiles/AdultandAdolescentGL.pdf. [Accessed 8 May 2012]

8. Steward WT, Remien RH, Higgins JA, Dubrow R, Pinkerton SD, Sikkema KJ, et al. Behavior change following diagnosis with acute/early HIV infection-a move to serosorting with other HIV-infected individuals. The NIMH Multisite Acute HIV Infection Study: III. AIDS Behav 2009; 13:1054–1060.

9. Branson B, Handsfield H, Lampe M, Janssen R, Taylor A, Lyss S, Clark J. Revised recommendations for HIV testing of adults, adolescents, and pregnant women in health-care settings. 2006. http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/rr5514a1.htm. [Accessed 21 November 2012]

10. CDC. HIV testing among men who have sex with men--21 cities, United States, 2008.MMWR 2012; 60:694–699.

11. Walensky RP, Weinstein MC, Kimmel AD, Seage R, George R, Losina E, et al. Routine human immunodeficiency virus testing: an economic evaluation of current guidelines. Am J Med 2005; 118:292–300.

12. Thompson MA, Aberg JA, Cahn P, Montaner JS, Rizzardini G, Telenti A, et al. Antiretroviral treatment of adult HIV infection: 2010 recommendations of the International AIDS Society-USA panel. JAMA 2010; 304:321–333.

13. Lee CP, Chertow GM, Zenios SA. An empiric estimate of the value of life: updating the renal dialysis cost-effectiveness standard. Value Health 2009; 12:80–87.

14. CDC. FDA-approved rapid HIV antibody screening tests.http://www.cdc.gov/hiv/topics/testing/rapid/rt-comparison.htm. [Accessed 8 May 2012].

15. Weinstein MC, Siegel JE, Gold MR, Kamlet MS, Russell LB. Recommendations of the panel on cost-effectiveness in health and medicine. JAMA 1996; 276:1253–1258.

16. United States. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Dept. of Labor. Consumer price index. http://www.bls.gov/cpi/. [Accessed 8 May 2012]

17. Gillick MR. Medicare coverage for technological innovations: time for new criteria?. N Engl J Med 2004; 350:2199–2203.

18. Pinkerton SD, Bogart LM, Howerton D, Snyder S, Becker K, Asch SM. Cost of OraQuick oral fluid rapid HIV testing at 35 community clinics and community-based organizations in the USA. AIDS Care 2009; 21:1157–1162.

19. Hall HI, Song R, Rhodes P, Prejean J, An Q, Lee LM, et al. Estimation of HIV incidence in the United States. JAMA 2008; 300:520–529.

20. Prejean J, Song R, Hernandez A, Ziebell R, Green T, Walker F, et al. Estimated HIV Incidence in the United States, 2006–2009. PLoS One 2011; 6:e17502.

21. Lieb S, White S, Grigg BL, Thompson DR, Liberti TM, Fallon SJ. Estimated HIV incidence, prevalence, and mortality rates among racial/ethnic populations of men who have sex with men, Florida. J Acquir Immune Defic Syndr 2010; 54:398–405.

22. Stall R, Duran L, Wisniewski SR, Friedman MS, Marshal MP, McFarland W, et al. Running in place: implications of HIV incidence estimates among urban men who have sex with men in the United States and other industrialized countries. AIDS Behav 2009; 13:615–629.

23. CDC. Analysis of testing results reported by laboratories participating in the model performance evaluation program for HIV-1 antibody during January 2008.http://wwwn.cdc.gov/mpep/pdf/hiv/0801HIV-1final.pdf. [Accessed 8 May 2012]

24. Mylonakis E, Paliou M, Lally M, Flanigan TP, Rich JD. Laboratory testing for infection with the human immunodeficiency virus: established and novel approaches. Am J Med 2000; 109:568–576.

25. WHO. HIV assays: operational characteristics: report 16 rapid assays. [http://www.who.int/diagnostics_laboratory/publications/Report16_final.pdf. [Accessed 8 May 2012]

26. Fox J, White PJ, Macdonald N, Weber J, McClure M, Fidler S, et al. Reductions in HIV transmission risk behaviour following diagnosis of primary HIV infection: a cohort of high-risk men who have sex with men. HIV Med 2009; 10:432–438.

27. The National Institute of Mental Health Multisite HIV Prevention Trial Group. The NIMH multisite HIV prevention trial: reducing HIV sexual risk behavior.Science 1998; 280:1889–1894.

28. Lyles RH, Munoz A, Yamashita T. Natural history of human immunodeficiency virus type 1 viremia after seroconversion and proximal to AIDS in a large cohort of homosexual men. J Infect Dis 2000; 181:872–880.

29. Prins M, Robertson JR, Brettle RP, Aguado IH, Broers B, Boufassa F, et al. Do gender differences in CD4 cell counts matter?. AIDS 1999; 13:2361–2364.

30. Mussini C, Cossarizza A, Sabin C, Babiker A, De Luca A, Bucher HC, et al. Decline of CD4+ T-cell count before start of therapy and immunological response to treatment in antiretroviral-naive individuals. AIDS 2011; 25:1041–1049.

31. Phillips AN, Lampe FC, Smith CJ, Geretti A-M, Rodger A, Lodwick RK, et al. Ongoing changes in HIV RNA levels during untreated HIV infection: implications for CD4 cell count depletion. AIDS 2010; 24:1561–1567.

32. Wolbers M, Babiker A, Sabin C, Young J, Dorrucci M, Chêne G, et al. Pretreatment CD4 cell slope and progression to AIDS or death in HIV-infected patients initiating antiretroviral therapy: the CASCADE collaboration: a collaboration of 23 cohort studies. PLoS Med 2010; 7:e1000239.

33. Forsyth AD, Valdiserri RO. Reaping the prevention benefits of highly active antiretroviral treatment: policy implications of HIV Prevention Trials Network 052. Curr Opin HIV AIDS 2012; 7:111–116.

34. Marks G, Gardner LI, Craw J, Crepaz N. Entry and retention in medical care among HIV-diagnosed persons: a meta-analysis. AIDS 2010; 24:2665–2678.

Keywords:

cost-effectiveness; HIV; modelling; screening; test-and-treat

Supplemental Digital Content

Back to Top | Article Outline

© 2013 Lippincott Williams & Wilkins, Inc.

Login

Search for Similar Articles
You may search for similar articles that contain these same keywords or you may modify the keyword list to augment your search.